IN THE MOUNTAIN"S SHADOW
Japan’s Silk Reelers Blazed an Asian Path of Economic
Development
by Yoichi Shimatsu
* The founding faculty member of the Journalism and Media Studies Centre at The University of Hong
Kong;
* Lecturer in English-language news reporting at the School of Journalism and Communication at
Tsinghua University in Beijing, China
Abstract: Exploring the history of the silk-reeling industry in Chichibu, Japan, this paper
challenges the prevalent representation of mountain communities as marginal economic
peripheries of the metropolitan center or as reservoirs of poverty and backwardness.
Mountain districts were the cradle of an Asian “industrious” revolution that led to Japan’s
modernization. The highland-based silk-reeling producers pioneered an autonomous
Asian model of industrial development, which competed successfully against the capital-
intensive system introduced from the West into coastal cities. The export strength of silk-
producing households in upland villages overturns the claim that Japan’s economic
miracle was based on the introduction of Western technology and administrative
systems. To the contrary, the Asian-style management practices and labor standards
developed by the silk producers were transferred to a succession of other industries.
These indigenous practices account for the rise of Japanese industry in world markets.
The clash between the two opposing models of modernization resulted in modern Japan’s
first major civil conflict, the Chichibu Rebellion of 1884, a legacy that has major
implications for today’s recession-mired Japan as well as for developing countries striving
for an alternative path to economic development.
1 Introduction: A Dissonant Fragment
On entering Chichibu, many visitors feel as if they were passing through a time warp into
another country or a bygone era as the train leaves behind Tokyo’s crowded suburbs and
winds through steep slopes forested with oaks, beeches and cedars. The Oku Chichibu
highlands, however, are a mere 70 kilometers northwest of Tokyo, or about 50 minutes by
rail, less than the average two-hour of daily commute of “salarymen” within metropolitan
area. The sense of separation between one of the world’s largest cities and this mountain
community is a holdover of Chichibu’s past geographical isolation. Stretched along an
east-west axis, the Oku Chichibu range ( note: The major peaks of the region include
Mitsumine, Kumotori and Kobushidake, with dozens of others ranging between 1,000
meters to 2,200 meters ) was an imposing barrier to overland travel until a tunnel was
blasted through the rock in the 1930s. Before then, travelers had to take a roundabout
riverboat journey of several days from the capital, located on the Ara River delta,
upstream past Kawagoe and Yorii to the upper reaches in Chichibu.
The first landmark after crossing Ashigakubo tunnel is the step pyramid of Buko Peak (
Chichibu Cement Company, now Taiheiyo Cement Corp., was established in 1923 as a
cooperative venture between Kami-Kagemori village and the Jobu Railway Co. (now
Chichibu Railway Corp.) then based in Kumagaya, Saitama Prefecture. ) sculpted by
dynamite blasts and a fleet of dump trucks that haul away the limestone, part of a
primordial seabed, to gigantic crushers and kilns. Vast beyond comprehension,
Bukozan’s cavity gave birth to the metropolis of Tokyo that rose out of the ashes of the
Great Kanto Earthquake of 1923 and the embers of World War II. Bukozan is a
monument to the greatest achievement of modernity, the concrete city.
Japan’s emergence as the first industrial power in Asia was centered in its treaty ports
located in the fertile lowlands along the Pacific coast: Tokyo -Yokohama, Osaka-Kobe,
Nagoya, Hiroshima and Nagasaki. The conventional view of Japanese history asserts that
these ports, which opened to Western commerce in 1859, became export -oriented
centers as a result of the Meiji reformers’ drive to introduce technology and modern
capitalist administrative standards from the United States and Europe. Factories,
infrastructure, electrical power and communications were concentrated in the port cities,
while raw materials for the industrialization drive, as well as labor power, were extracted
from the mountainous hinterlands. The ports were thus the center of industrialization,
while the mountain communities were relegated to the economic periphery.
Modernization is interpreted as a triumph of a progressive Western civilization, albeit
borrowed by and adapted to a local culture, over a backward and feudal Asiatic mode of
production. Economic planners in many developing countries have since adopted the
“Japanese model” of modernization, sacrificing traditional local manufactures for the
benefit of Western- style industrialization.
This narrative of externally promoted industrialization is flawed by a “fragment that part of
the totality of the work that opposes totality”(Adorno, Theodor 1970). The dissonant
element is silk, Japan’s main export from the 1850’s through the early 1960’s. The hard
currency needed to finance Japan’s Western-style “industrial revolution” largely came
from traditional industry of silk- reeling as well as other textile work. Chichibu, I was to
discover after several years of residence there, was in fact the cradle of modern Japanese
industry, along with other mountain districts. The economic and social influence of this
silk-growing mountain district is not immediately apparent to weekend trekkers or even to
a transplant like myself, who choose the place for a writer’s cottage because of its
forests and low land prices. The evidence of a dynamic economic history lies hidden from
sight, in some ways more obscure than Troy was to Schiemann since there is little of a
literary tradition or official record of its past existence.
My first sight of this buried industrial architecture was of a black-and-white photo in my
realtor’s office. Taken about a century earlier, it shows the old downtown area, then called
Omiya, bristling with smokestacks with denuded dark mountains in the background. The
dismal landscape looked like one of Dickens’ coal- mining towns rather than the hikers’
paradise that it is today. Kunio Machida, an energetic entrepreneur of many parts –
builder, forester, political campaigner and local history buff – corrected my misperception.
“There weren’t as many evergreens in those days as there are now, because the old-
timers coppiced nara and other oaks for high-quality charcoal,” Machida said ( Kunio
Machida, interview, 13 February 2002 ). The present- day evergreen groves, as natural as
they seem to be, are actually plantations introduced after World War II, while the stands
of native oaks have been greatly reduced. The postwar cedar planting was a state-
planned campaign in anticipation of a housing boom, which happened but with cheaper
lumber from Southeast Asia and North America. Until the 1950s, the upper slopes were
reserved for mulberry bushes, Machida explained, up to the 1,400-meter altitude of the
highest postwar timber plantations, an extraordinary elevation given the cold winters in
these climes. The upland villagers slashed and burned the precipitous mountainsides to
enrich the soil with the ashes of broadleaf trees, yielding a summer feast for their
silkworms.
The inroads of Tokyo’s economic planners reshaped the natural order, and the impact of
their policies was even greater on the local community. Mrs. Obitsu, ( Obitsu family
interviews, 11 January 2002. In the Edo Era, the village of Niegawa, or “River of
Sacrifices,” linked the boat landing on the upper reaches of the Arakawa with the path to
Mitsumine Shrine and the post road over the mountains to Nagano and Kyoto .) a
resident of Niegawa village, told me that her family had raised silkworms for many
generations until the 1960's, as did every other household in the village. This accounted
for the large size of the older houses because cocoons had to be protected indoors in the
late autumn, she said. The large two-story homes in the recesses of the Oku Chichibu
range are remnants of a social order more complex and culturally richer than the present-
day landscape pitted with quarries, flooded by damming and emptied of people. What
was destroyed in the space of less than 50 years had taken centuries to perfect.
Sericulture over the Centuries
Silkworms were introduced to Chichibu in the murky Kofun era (250 AD600 AD), named
after the huge tumuli, or burial mounds for aristocrats. The area was already known then
for shirokinu, or white silk, according to Chichibu Meisen Museum curator Keiji
Yokoyama. The oral history related to Koma Shrine, in the foothills east of Chichibu,
indicates that silk production and dyeing began in earnest during the Heian Era with the
arrival of Korean craftsmen around 700 AD, relatively late in the history of the Silk Road
that once linked East Asia with West Asia and Europe ( Keiji Yokoyama, curator,
Chichibu Meisen Museum, interviews on 24 & 25 February 2002 ). The founding of
dozens of Buddhist temples in the Chichibu highlands in the Kamakura Era (13th 14th
century) indicates the growing importance of the silk economy despite the isolation of the
mountainous district. Its remoteness was implied by legends of defeated samurai of the
Taira clan and later the warlord Masakado’s forces who fled up the Ara River, where they
were received shelter from the mountain folk, establishing a tradition of defiance to
governing authorities.
In the Edo Era (17th-19th century), the dual payment system that governed taxation and
trade spurred the growth of a cash economy in Chichibu and other silk- producing
mountain districts. The anomaly of a thriving cash economy under a feudal political
structure has been a persistent source of dispute among economic historians, who
created the ambiguous category of “premodern” to describe the Edo economy. From the
start of their regime, the Tokugawa shoguns imposed a rice levy on the local fiefdoms run
by daimyo, or fief lords, since a predictable supply of staple foodstuffs was the very
rationale for the feudal social order, known as the bakuhan system. A food surplus was
needed not only for the warrior class but also to maintain the corvee labor system, which
provided the manpower to build the waterworks, roadways, bridges, docks and fortresses
of the great urban centers Osaka and Edo (Tokyo).
The merchant houses, which supplied the swelling city population with food, fuel, clothing
and entertainment, conducted commercial transactions through a credit arrangement
based on promissory notes, which were ultimately guaranteed by silver or gold coins. The
newly urbanized samurai-bureaucrats quickly acquired bourgeois tastes for luxurious
garments and house wares. As a result of rising urban consumption, the cash economy
penetrated the mountainous districts, which were poor in rice but abundant in metal ores,
dyes and silk. To combat inflation caused by the rising price of textiles imported from
China (Miyamae Hideki 1990), the new shogunate in 1628 banned farmers from wearing
silk clothing and nine years later drastically reduced the inflow of Chinese silk by closing
the port of Nagasaki (Heita Kawakatsu asserts that sakoku was imposed to regulate
trade rather than completely cut off the Japanese economy from foreign commerce. ).
The shogunate’s spartan dress code came under assault from the kabukimono, riotous
samurai dandies who defied convention by wearing outrageous costumes in the
entertainment quarters. The lower classes used more subversive means to resist the
artificial suppression of demand. Consigned to drab hues, the plebeians wore their colors
in bold bands or lined their cloaks with silk prints hidden from public view. The dress rules
were bent to the breaking point with the spread of meisen, a hybrid textile made of hemp
or cotton in the woof and silk in the weft. Chichibu was a major center of production of
meisen for kimono and nassen, used to cover sleeping pads and mats. Most of this trade
apparently went on within an informal economy outside of official controls.
The popular resistance to austerity was, at one level, a political protest against arbitrary
authority but also, in line with the Zen arts tradition, a call for creative expression in all
aspects of daily life. As art critic Shuichi Kato put it: “Traditional Japanese culture was
structured, so to speak, with its aesthetic values at its core (Kato, Shuichi 1971). The
sixth shogun Tsunayoshi, a dandified esthete, took the path of least resistance in 1713
by enacting an edict promoting silk production. A key measure was to allow taxes for
industrial crops including silk and tobacco to be paid for in cash rather than rice. With the
lowlands given over to intensive rice production, the mountainous regions possessed the
only untapped land available for cash crops. Uesugi Yosan, daimyo of Yonezawa in
mountainous Yamagata, is an exemplar of local leaders who promoted industrial crops.
Likewise, the Oshi family, a branch of the Hojo clan based at Yorii castle on the Ara
River, strongly favored cash crops in the Chichibu uplands. Overshadowed by the east-
west ridgeline, the river valley lacked sufficient sunlight for rice or other staple foods.
Thus, by the late Edo era, 70 percent of Chichibu households were producing silk. In
most cases, single households vertically integrated all steps from growing mulberries to
raising cocoons and silk reeling, and relied primarily on the labor of the extended family
but also included wage laborers from neighboring homes. This level of organization was
more complex than “cottage industry.” The mountain folk did not abandon their
subsistence economy and continued to grow barley, millet, buckwheat, chestnuts,
radishes and cabbages, a traditional practice still prevalent in the Chichibu highlands.
Silk-growing, however, was the primary driver of rising living standards, better education
and a surprisingly rich cultural life, as displayed at the annual Chichibu festival. The mid-
December festival at Chichibu Shrine became a market-day for silk traders, who rigorous
graded the product before delivering it to the capital Edo. By 1789 there were 83 retailers
in Edo specializing in Chichibu silk. (Saitama Journalists Association). Total sales
reached 27,971 gold ryo, a huge sum considering that the theft of 10 ryo was punishable
with the death penalty. ( The value of the oval ryo coin in the Tokugawa period was
roughly about 5 koku, or bushel of rice. One koku was the annual food supply for a
samurai.) Through this market system, mountain areas were closely connected with the
urban center through a division of labor and sophisticated system of financing, bypassing
the feudal economy of the fertile lowlands. While the lowland peasants remained bound to
the rice economy, the mountain folk were organizing their households as productive
business enterprises and operating in a cash economy.
The Case for Asian Modernity
The predominant viewpoint in Japanese studies is that the emerging industrial economy
of the Edo Era was “premodern” or merely the commercial extension of feudalism.
Economic historian Heita Kawakatsu disputes this notion of a premodern transition
existing phantom- like between feudalism and capitalism. The late Edo era, he argues,
gave rise to a productive revolution on par with the industrial revolution in Western Europe
and the United States. The modernization of Japan came about as the result of an
evolutionary process within Asian civilization rather than by emulation of the capitalist
West. (Kawakatsu’s arguments summarized here are largely drawn from his seminal
article Kindai sekai shisutemu to sakoku, Looking back on the Edo Period, (Bunka Kaigi
February 1992: 1022,Kawakatsu et al 1994,2000) Kawakatsu’s perspective finds ample
support in the experience of silk-producing mountain districts.
Unlike the tobacco and salt monopolies, the silk traders operated under commercial
license, which allowed the development of a market system, even if not on a strictly
laissez-faire basis. Under the supervision of shogunate officials, dealers renegotiated the
price of silk annually with consortia of producers. The consensus-based arrangement
cushioned both sides against the vicissitudes of nature and shocks of the market, and
fostered long-term business relationships. The predictable price structure gave the silk
growers 186 Page 5 Journal of Mountain Science Vol 1 No 2 (2004) confidence to borrow
from moneylenders ahead of the June-to-October growing season. The annual price-
setting scheme maximized the number of players with access to markets and loans, as
opposed to the winner-take-all rule of laissez- faire capitalism. The result was a
management system that promoted stable growth for a growing number of household
enterprises as opposed to a high-risk and high-reward Western system, which has been
acutely vulnerable to cyclical crises.
The rapid introduction of technology into the production process was the basis for the
industrial revolution in the West. As shown at a local museum in Yoshida-machi, the Edo
Era also put high value on technical innovation. In contrast to the Western preference for
iron and steel, early Japanese machines were made primarily from a mixture of traditional
materials and metal. The frames and moving parts of silk reels, threshers and bellows
were built mostly of wood or bamboo, and outfitted with steel blades for crushing or
cutting functions. The silk reel of the late Edo Era was so efficient that its basic design
has not been changed over the past century. The most significant innovation was the
substitution of human power with native waterwheels and later steam power and then
electricity, enabling silk workers to use both of their hands to gather silk threads. The
evolution of silk- reeling technology reveals one of the notable features of Japanese
industrialism: the incremental improvement of production technology by “skilful” workers.
The role of the “skilful” worker represents a major difference between the Asian and
Western models of industrialization in their respective management philosophies and in
the relationships between labor and capital.
In the West, as Max Weber pointed out, the entrepreneur has been exalted as a member
of a predestined elect whose faith was affirmed with hard work and accumulation of
capital. The result was a bias in favor of the capital congealed in the machine, while the
worker faced the steady loss of his social status from craftsman to unskilled laborer. The
Western factory is the meeting point of the smart machine and dull worker. The Japanese
model, on the other hand, has stressed the role of the “skilful” laborer who exercises a
significant degree of authority and responsibility over his tools and, collectively, over the
workspace and production process. (Takeshi Hamashita coined the term “industrious
revolution” to describe the labor-intensive model of Asian industrialization in Hamashita
T., Kawakatsu Heita et al 1991) Japanese-style management is rooted in the role of Edo
contractors who not only directed the flow of capital but, more importantly, served as
coordinators or middlemen (rather than omnipotent bosses) for a labor force that kept a
high degree of autonomy under household-centered production system. This tradition of
consensus decision-making was transferred to modern factories as one of the features of
the Japanese management system.
The nature of contracts also differed between East and West. “Free” labor in the West
was strictly quantified through the strict division of time within the workday. A time card
made the possible the hourly wage. Under the Asian system, terms of service were of
longer duration and subject to negotiation, a feature that survives in the lifetime
employment system and enterprise-based unions in corporate Japan. The incompatibility
of the Japanese and Western modes of production was based in the differing attitudes
toward the product, especially its value content. As shown in the popular resistance to
the dress code, the consumer esteemed the product not only for its utilitarian function but
also as an expressive medium.
The potential for goods to transcend social discourse and become pure art objects
reached its highest expression in the silk kimono, which with its properties of suppleness
and luster constitutes a surface charged with aura, or aesthetic value. The ambiguity of
the kimono – its lack of hard edges and non-utilitarian form – tends to hide a complex
production process that transforms 10,225 cocoons into an exquisite garment. How can
something so formless, imperceptible and indescribable as aesthetic value be defined?
“In the sound of silk,” said Keiji Yokoyama, curator of the new Chichibu Meisen Museum.
Tweed makes no such sound. Water resistant, hardy against the elements and subdued
enough to wear every day, Scottish woolens are a fine expression of the “ascetic spirit” of
Western capitalism, described by Max Weber. “This worldly Protestant asceticism
Yoichi Shimatsu acted powerfully against the spontaneous enjoyment of possessions; it
restricted consumption, especially of commodities,” Weber wrote. In a “rational” economy
modeled after the West, silk handicrafts should have immediately been killed off by the
introduction of cotton spinning and then rayon, yet the humble silk reelers survived the
great waves of industrialism. “As life changed (in Japan), different types of art dominated
in different periods, but the close relationship between art and daily life remained
unaltered,” write Shuichi Kato. “Here question arises: How could such a relationship
survive in an industrial society?”
Silk Producers Revolt
A change of fashion can have more sweeping consequences than a war or revolution.
Whether hose covered the bareness left by rising hemlines or caused hemlines to rise is
a chicken-and-egg question. From the mid-19th century to the early 20th century,
millions of pairs of feminine legs from Paris to Peoria came out of concealment to be
revealed, or re- veiled, in translucent silk. Mass production of textiles had combined with
the persuasive power of the mass media to create the fashion industry in the industrial
capitals of Europe and North America. The demand for silk stockings in Western
countries resulted in Japan’s rapid emergence as a world trading power – and silk reeling
was the turnkey for the first Japanese economic miracle. Britain’s military campaigns
during the Opium War and Taiping Rebellion had devastated the once- robust Chinese
silk industry based in Suzhou. With the opening of Yokohama to foreign trade in 1859,
silk became the island country’s largest export and Japan the world’s biggest supplier. To
ensure quality control, the Maebashi domain north of Chichibu hired a Swiss expert to
design a Western-style silk mill, based on textile plants in the Turin and Rhone-Alps
region. Within a year of coming to power in 1869, the new Meiji government launched a
crash program to catch up with the Western powers. Besides building the country’s first
railroad and expanding its shipbuilding industry, the Tokyo authorities established a large
silk mill in Tomioka, Gunma. Caught up in the export fever, the private trading house Ono-
gumi opened a plant in Miyamada, Niigata. All of these mills along with other large-scale
industrial enterprises, directly owned or indirectly promoted by government, were financial
failures.
Western-style industry could not compete against Asian industriousness. The Western-
style mills failed to capture the silk export market because they could not obtain cocoons
from vertically integrated silk- producing households. Small-scale producers in Gunma
and Saitama had little incentive to sell cocoons to large mills because they earned larger
profits from selling skeins of reeled silk to contractors or directly through silk
manufacturers associations to merchants in Yokohama. Within a dozen years, the Meiji
modernization campaign resulted in a debt crisis fueled by costly technology imports and
by unproductive bond issues to support unemployed samurai left over from the feudal
domains. Runaway inflation caused Chichibu moneylenders to hike their rates on loans
taken out prior to the summer silkworm season. By 1881, interest rates had overtaken
annual profits of the growers in the Chichibu area, and silk production fell by more than 70
percent during the following three years. Unable to obtain loans, the debt-burdened
growers were reduced to selling cocoons to factories rather than finished silk to
exporters. The powerhouse of Japan’s modern economy was being crushed by an
inefficient and inappropriate factory system copied from the West.
The irreconcilable conflict between the Asian production mode and the newly introduced
Western system resulted in a civil war. In 1884, the silk growers of Yoshida-machi raised
a force of more than 8,000 rebels from across the Chichibu highlands to seek a debt
moratorium and official controls on inflation. Inspired by the example of the Paris
Commune, the leaders of the Chichibu Rebellion raised demands for universal suffrage
and parliamentary democracy to replace the rule of imperial ministers. When the national
government rejected their grievances, the rebels torched the storehouses of the
moneylenders and, armed with muskets and spades, fought against columns of armed
police and soldiers with breech- loading rifles. After a week of battle, the surviving rebels
retreated over mountain passes to rally support among silk growers in Nagano Prefecture
in the southern and central Japan Alps. On the eighth day of battle, a second army
column descending from Matsumoto trapped the rebels at the foot of Yatsugatake, killing
dozens. Some 3,800 men were found guilty of sedition and more common crimes, and
the leaders were executed.
The Meiji government and the press denounced the rebellion as a farmers’ riot rather than
a revolution. The Incident, as the locals call it, was the harbinger of modern democratic
movements that would sweep across Asia over the following century. The spiraling
inflation and popular rebellion in Chichibu forced the new finance minister, Matsukata
Masayoshi, to sell off the Western-style factories – including the failed textile plants – at
fire-sale prices and to impose currency controls. The silk mills were privatized and turned
over to large trading houses such as Mitsui. Silk production rapidly revived when
Yokohoma merchants began to extend loans to local silk manufacturers associations,
replacing the hated moneylenders.
Throughout the 1890s, household-based silk manufacturers associations accounted for
three-fourths of silk output in the prefectures of Gunma and Chichibu, as opposed to
Nagano, Aichi, Gifu and Yamanashi, where large-scale mills predominated. Single
households continued to efficiently compete against the Western-style mills by adapting
waterwheel power and other technical improvements. In 1901, however, the small
producers of Gunma were hit by the same nemesis as Chichibu 15 years earlier – a loan
crisis, this time caused by the collapse of a local bank.
Reeled silk and silk products were Japan’s major source of foreign exchange earnings,
accounting for 36 percent of total export earnings from 1881-1893. This income was
extremely important to counterbalance the rising import demand during the early phase of
industrialization, and enabled the national economy to register a slight trade balance in
these difficult times (Yamazaki, Ippei 1998). The total number of silk-reeling mills rose
from 336,224 in 1894 when figures were first tallied until a peak of 421,913 in 1900. Strict
quality control standards imposed by silk merchants caused attrition in the number of
machine reeling-factories as well as hand-reeling shops, the former shrinking by half from
1905 to 1926 while the smaller operations were reduced by two thirds over the same
period (Institute of Development Economics 1969). The worldwide Great Depression was
preceded by the 1926-27 financial downturn in Japan, which resulted in halving the
number of hand-reeling shops from 131,789 in 1925 to 66,249 in 1927. The better-
financed machine-reeling factories took advantage of this crisis for small producers, and
increased in number from the low point of 3,509 factories in 1928 to 3,738 in 1930. The
number of farm households engaged in cocoon raising rose from 1.67 million in 1915,
when nationwide annual figures were first reported, to a peak of 2.2 million in 1929, when
the Great Depression drastically reduced the volume of international trade. Total raw silk
production in Japan continued to rise, however, until 1934, buoyed somewhat by the
thriving sari trade with the British- controlled Indian subcontinent. Throughout the crises of
the worldwide depression and Japanese military intervention in China, hand-reeling shops
survived despite gradual attrition to 26,735 units by 1940, the last year statistics on this
sector were compiled.
The decline of household production was, therefore, not the result of inefficient allocation
of labor, machinery or management skills. The Asian model of industrialization came
under assault from an unrealistic industrialization policy and fiscal mismanagement, as
well as the military repression by a national government that was taking a course of
aggression that culminated in the Pacific War. From this perspective, the non- militaristic
economic growth of postwar Japan – reflected in the so-called Japanese management
system – can be interpreted as a partial return to a more balanced Asian model of
modernization.
Women Workers in Industrial Society
The proponents of a Western-led “global system” have never tried to argue that the factory
system improved the living standards of Japanese silk workers. An undeniable piece of
evidence of labor relations in Western-style mills is preserved in the Chichibu Municipal
Folklore Museum: a seven-year labor contract for a nine-year-old girl sent to a Chichibu
mill by her parents from the Tohoku region for a sum of 30 yen. The feature film “Nomugi
Pass” depicts how young women from mountain communities in Nagano Prefecture
endured the harsh conditions of the Western- style mills, where indoor steam and
dormitory crowding created a breeding ground for tuberculosis and other respiratory
diseases. The popular movie also showed the other side of factory life, as mountain
women extended their sense of community solidarity into the economic relations of the
factory and fought for labor rights. (Depicting the lives of silk reelers in the Okaya district
of Suwa, Nagano, Nomugi Toge, Nomugi Pass, directed by Satsuo Yamamoto, was shot
on location at the Hasegawa silk mill in Yonezawa, Yamagata. The 1979 film was
inspired by the first strike in Kofu, Gunma.) The first industrial strike in Japan was
organized in 1885 by female silk reelers in Gunma Prefecture ( Tsurumi, Patricia 1990 ).
In contrast to other mountain districts, large mills never dominated silk production in
Chichibu. From the 1920s through the late 1960s, more than 560 mills and dye works
were operating in central Chichibu and the outlying town of Takashino. Nearly all
enterprises were family-owned, and 58 percent had less than five employees, according
to the Chichibu Meisen Museum. Although a large share of local silk continued to be
produced for export, Chichibu’s weaving industry also produced cushion covers and
meisen for the domestic market. Chichibu’s silk industry was eventually doomed by the
postwar craze for Western clothing and lifestyles, a trend bolstered by advertising and the
media. Fashion, this time around, proved to be fatal. Today, the mills are gone. In
Takashino, a handful of surviving mill buildings are now used as warehouses. Some 50
cocoon growers still produce cocoons for surviving mills in Gunma and Fukushima
prefectures.
Silkworm grower Yoshio Takagishi of Kami-Yoshida- machi, takes pride in his eco-
friendly farm where the spent logs for growing mushrooms are later burned as fuel to heat
his silkworm sheds. The middle-aged grower is a living link with history, being a
descendant of Takagishi Zenkichi, a leader of the Chichibu Rebellion (Yoshio Takagishi,
interview, 28 February 2002). The strongest evidence for the continuing existence of the
Asian economic model now has only a tenuous connection with silk. The “skilful labor”
from the silk industry was literally transferred to the watch- making and electronic
industries, as former silk workers moved into the new factories in Chichibu in the 1960s
and ‘70s. Silk grower Yoshio Takagishi said that the declining demand for silk means that
sericulture could survive for only another 15 years in Chichibu, that is, until his generation
retires. Keiji Yokoyama, curator of the Chichibu Meisen Museum, is pessimistic about
the possibility of younger generations of Japanese abandoning a Western-style lifestyle
based on convenience. Curator Yokoyama notes that India retains the silk sari as the
daily garment because “Indians unlike the Japanese have retained their indigenous
lifestyle.” The loss of cultural tradition is having an adverse economic impact on younger
people, since the domestic textile industry, once a major employer, cannot provide new
jobs. Clothing design is a component of what economic historian Heita Kawakatsu calls a
“set” of goods that constitute a lifestyle. Fashion decisions are not simply based on
volition but involve the marketing campaigns and distribution systems of trading
companies, which profit by importing cotton and wool produced by agribusiness while
marginalizing textiles like silk and hemp grown in small mountain communities. The
irreconcilable divergence between two paths of economic development continues to
fester, as Japan remains stuck in a long-term industrial recession.
Conclusion:A Need to Examine the Economies of Mountain
Communities
The example of Chichibu points to the need to re- examine the economic history of
mountain communities, a study far beyond the modest geographical scope of this
discussion. It can be said, however, that the studies of mountainous regions such as
Kashmir and Himalayan Nepal have mostly focused on environment and culture, without
exploring the economic relationship between these elements. Kashmir has been one of
the wealthiest regions of India, in spite of the pressures of political division, communal
conflict and popular insurgency. Its traditional prosperity was based on the fine wool of its
mountain goats, woven into cashmere fabric, as well as silk embroidery. Despite the
harm done to India’s calico producers under English colonial trade laws, Kashmir’s
isolation and separate political status allowed its textile industry to prosper with exports
to Britain. The Newaris of the Kathmandu valley is another example of a community that
excelled in the metalworking trades, creating a rich urban culture and maintaining an
extensive trade with the Tibetan plateau and the agrarian Terai plains. What these
communities have in common was the ability to add value to their mountain- based
resources, establish niche industries and use the cash economy to their advantage in
trading with lowland cities and foreign markets.
Mountains have also proven to be the undoing of both communities, with warfare along
the Himalayan Line of Control for the Kashmiris and the Cold War’s reduction of trade
between Nepal and Tibet for the Newaris. Tourism has largely substituted in both cases
for the pre- existing regional trade, distorting to some degree the economic self-
development potential of these communities with an artificial overemphasis on handicrafts
rather than local industry. The larger problem remains, however, in the industrial policies
of central governments, which tend to favor state-owned or insider monopolies at the
expense of local producers.
Studies of the traditional economic dynamics of mountain communities could lead to a
better understanding of their potential for industrial self- development, as well as more
sustainable trade links with the developed countries. In its early development drive,
Japan’s homegrown industry proved to be the basis for economic growth rather than a
disadvantage. “The industrial component ratio of textiles (in the “cottage” sector) in Japan
in the earlier years were higher than in ever seen in the present-day developing countries.”
(Ishikawa, Shigeru 1969.) The retreat of NGOs and tourism before the ongoing Nepalese
hill people’s insurgency, reminiscent of the Chichibu Rebellion, shows that external
dependency relations, no matter how well intended or ideally conceived, cannot
substitute for indigenous industry rooted in the environment and culture of mountain
communities.
References
Adorno, Theodor. 1970. Aesthetic Theory. Minneapolis:University of Minnesota Press.
Hamashita T., Kawakatsu Heita et al. 1991. Ajia koekiken tonihon kogyoka, 1500-1900,
In: The Asian Trading Sphere and Japan’s Industrialization. Tokyo: Libro Port.
Ishikawa, Shigeru. 1969. Economic Development in the Asian Perspective. Tokyo:
Hitotsubashi University. Pp 425-427.
Institute of Development Economics. 1969. One Hundred Years of Agricultural Statistics
in Japan 1969. TokyoPp.171-173.
Kawakatsu H. 1992a. The National Seclusion Policy Reappraised, Japan Echo 19(2):
6576.
Kawakatsu et al, 1994. Japanese Industrialization and the Asian Economy,London:
Routledge.
Kawakatsu et al, 2000. Asia Pacific Dynamism, London:Routledge. 1550-2000.
Kato Shuichi. 1971. Form, Style, Tradition: Reflections on Japanese Art and Society.
Tokyo: Kodansha International. Pp 4.
Miyamae Hideki. 1990. Timeline of Silk History. Chichibu, Japan: Yoshida-machi Rekishi
Minzoku Shiryokan (Yoshida Town Residents History Archives)
Saitama Journalists Association. 1966.
Saitama Rural Almanac.Urawa, Japan
Tsurumi E. Patricia. 1990. Factory Girls: Women in the Thread Mills of Meiji Japan.
Rutgers, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Pp. 50-58.
Yamazaki Ippei. 1998. Raw-Silk Exports and Japanese Economic Development. In:
Smitka M. et al, The Textile Industry and the Rise of the Japanese Economy. NewYork,
Garland Publishing. Pp 51-67.
|